A politician's -- and citizen's -- guide
to urban transportation
Care about traffic? Read this guide.
by Gordon Price [and comments
by SDCTC]
|
|
ity the politician who promises to fix the urban transportation
problem. Traffic congestion may be their constituents' constant
frustration, but given the resources and policy levers available
to local government, there's only so much that can be done, and
it's not nearly enough.
We can't
just build our way out of congestion [although in San Diego we
are still trying], and so we speak highly of alternative transportation
options and better land-use policies. But these take time, and
meanwhile drivers demand action. Their conclusion: someone do
something!
Voters,
however, want their infrastructure carrots before the fiscal
sticks. Yet given the nature of our vehicle-based transportation
system, with continually expanding demand, concrete solutions
are often temporary or ineffectual -- and staggeringly expensive.
A billion dollars isn't much in the transportation game.
Politicians
intuitively appreciate that transportation policy is rooted in
feelings. Feelings about our cars, feelings about our homes and
neighborhoods (places made possible by the car), and feelings
(often guilt or frustration) about the consequences of our choices.
Expectations
and emotions are shaped by advertising; issues are framed by
media. Without an appreciation of the often unrecognized assumptions
inherent in our auto-centric society, we won't understand the
real nature of the problem.
|
|
|
THE PROBLEM
The Critical Expectation
|
|
Politicians
are faced with a paradox: the pursuit of self-interest leads
to unfortunate collective consequences that threaten the individual
benefits achieved. Simply put: As more people want to drive the
open road, the less likely it is for the road to be open.
Vehicle
miles traveled around the United States have increased by 70
percent over the last 20 years, compared with a two percent increase
in new highway construction. The US General Accounting Office
predicts that road congestion in the United States will triple
in 15 years, even if capacity is increased by 20 percent.
In the
Greater Vancouver Regional District, peak traffic volume is estimated
to rise 60 percent in the next two decades -- and that's after
we've made substantial improvements and added capacity to both
our road and transit systems. [The San Diego region is forecasting
"vehicle miles of travel" will grow by 47%.]
Yet advertising,
that most powerful of influences, markets mobility and freedom.
We see the most beautiful images of the car on the open road.
Those ads sell many things --- and youth -- but every ad reinforces
one big idea: the car is never constrained by an excess number
of other cars. You never see the car caught in congestion.
The freely
moving car on the open road is one of our society's most hallowed
images, synonymous with success, reinforced over many generations,
marketed to the world -- and yet increasingly frustrated at every
turn. Cars and trucks are getting bigger and more powerful, engineered
to be capable of speeds well beyond any legal limit, even as
the roads become more clogged and average speeds decrease. This
disconnect between promise and reality has produced responses
of both rage and passivity, with an underlying sense of betrayal.
This is not the way it was supposed to be.
People
have always assumed that, as we buy more cars, we will build
more roads. Each purchaser takes for granted that there will
always be room for one more. Always room for one more -- an assumption
that there will be essentially unlimited capacity.
That is
what traffic engineers have been trained for: to provide enough
capacity to meet demand, which, if there is always room for one
more, must be theoretically infinite. Their job is to translate
infinity into reality.
In fact,
engineers are never asked to determine what the upper limit on
capacity should be -- and how we could maintain that limit --
so that the vehicles that do use a properly managed system could
function efficiently. To do so would imply a limit on the number
of cars that can be served, and hence destroy the illusion on
which the car industry and our planning is based.
|
The Practical Limit
|
|
Constituents
expect problems of congestion to be solved, but not at their
individual expense. People want carrots, not sticks -- but don't
want to pay for expensive carrots and don't want the sticks to
hurt. Each wants the other to use transit.
The politician
is caught between the expectation that enough room needs to be
provided for an ever-increasing number of vehicles and the reality
that there is not enough space, tax dollars or community support
to do so.
Consider,
for instance, the growth in vehicles in the Greater Vancouver
Regional District. Currently, there are 1.1 million motor-vehicles.
Each year that number increases by about 23,000 -- 63 more vehicles
per day, about three per hour, another car or truck every 20
minutes. [Currently, there are about 1.88 million motor vehicles
in San Diego County. That number is expected to grow by an average
of about 34,000 cars a year over the next 20 years -- 94 more
vehicles per day, about four per hour, another car or truck every
15 minutes.]
The average
car length is about 15 feet. We'd need another 65 miles of asphalt
just to park a year's worth of cars, and about 260 miles of single-lane
roadway if they were all to drive safely at 30 mph.
To be conservative,
let's cut the demand to a tenth of that. If we wanted to build
only 26 miles (42 km) of new roadway by widening existing roads
by one lane each (say, five arterials in Vancouver), we would
have to spend (very conservatively) about $20 million in construction
costs. [We'd need over 97 miles of asphalt in San Diego just
to park a year's worth of cars bumper to bumper -- or, if you
want to have enough parking at your likely destinations, about
1.84 square miles. That's the equivalent of over 1,200 miles
of on-street parking. We'd need 389 miles of single-lane roadway
if they were all to drive safely at 30 mph.]
But the
real expense is land, particularly along the routes on which
the traffic concentrates -- those that lead to the town center.
Since almost all roads leading into Downtown Vancouver have residential
zoning along them (and the average house price in Vancouver is
$343,000), a billion dollars might get us most of the way if
we were to purchase the houses on one side of five arterials
running through the city (say, First, Renfrew, Knight/Clark,
Oak and Gran-ville -- equal to about one year's demand for road
space) to widen them by one lane.
The political
prospects of that scenario is something less than zero. Even
trying to acquire a few feet of property for a left-hand-turn
bay at a major intersection can take years. If expropriation
is required, the City would certainly end up paying massive legal
fees -- and the prospect of forcibly evicting thousands of people
to widen roads is out of the question.
Even after
the roads are widened, the real need for space remains largely
unmet. The car must be parked, usually many times a day, and
there must be a piece of asphalt waiting at every destination.
If underground, the cost of a single parking space easily exceeds
$15,000. If surface, then the land must be cheap and the densities
low in order to provide sufficient space.
Parking
standards have driven urban design for most of the century. The
need for wide roads and abundant parking is the reason why the
endless strips of commercial frontage now appear everywhere and
why the dominant form of commerce is the decorated box in the
midst of the asphalt parking lot, with the big sign out front
to attract the speeding passerby.
|
Who pays?
|
|
Given the
limits to road expansion, it's no surprise, then, that every
car added to the road means less remaining space for those already
there. That makes the space more valuable as it becomes scarcer.
So what do we do?
We give
it away for free. There's no cost to use the road, no matter
how much space is used or how often -- unlike the per-trip cost
of transit and taxis. Consequently, there's an incentive to take
advantage of unfilled road space. And so it is.
Take, for
example, the Ford Excursion, the biggest sport-utility vehicle
ever, over 19 feet long. Ford makes more than C$20,000 pre-tax
profit with each sale, significantly more than the profit on
smaller cars. But Ford does not pay a cent to any municipality
to build the additional space its product requires, save for
the property tax on its dealerships. If Ford had to pay Vancouver
for the marginal cost of the space the Excursion will take up,
the vehicle would cost $60,000 but the marginal cost of the new
space could be $106,000.
It is the
local taxpayer who will pay, not the automobile company -- the
same local taxpayer who, though willing to spend tens of thousands
of dollars for a new car, would be distressed at the prospect
of paying hundreds of dollars in new taxes for more road space
if charged directly at the time of sale.
So the
cars and trucks keep coming, they keep getting bigger, and the
expectation remains that government will build and maintain the
needed road space, and it will get the money largely from local
taxpayers. And it can't be done.
|
A charge by other means
|
|
From the
individual's point of view, driving more and driving longer continues
to make sense. Why? Because the roadway is seen to be "free"
-- and so, typically, is the next trip. The marginal cost of
the car is practically zero, at least when measured by the amount
of money taken out of pocket. Except for the occasional cost
of parking (over 90 percent of parking is free for most people),
everything else has been covered -- purchase price, insurance,
gas -- regardless of how much may be owed. The next trip appears
to cost nothing... and we tend to use a lot of something that
seems to be free.
Because
the price of highway space is so low, we pay by other means.
Just as cheap land leads to sprawl and cheap energy to pollution,
cheap road space has led to congestion. Congestion is the means
by which we price the value of the space. It works, but we hate
it.
Many economists
and environmentalists have suggested "road pricing"
as a more rational way to allocate a scarce resource. But pricing
the road is a touchy political problem. The road is our commons.
No matter who you are, you have the same right to the road. Rich
or poor, powerful or weak, you are equal, even if you're caught
in the same congestion. Especially when you're caught in the
same congestion. To price the road on a per-trip or distance
basis would change the status of road users. People would no
longer feel equal.
Both the
rich and poor feel they have a stake in the free roadway and
the cheap car. To maintain the auto as a low-cost form of transportation
means the poor meet the rich on common ground, while the de-facto
subsidy for the rich remains disproportionately large. The left
defends the free road so the poor can drive farther for cheaper
housing and needed work. The right opposes the tax grab that
road pricing would entail. The politician has little ground on
which to stand.
We are
confronted with a dilemma of our own making: limited resources,
infinite demand. The only realistic tool we have -- congestion
-- is seen as the problem, not as a necessary consequence. Those
who benefit don't proportionately pay, and don't want to. We
look for rational solutions for a problem largely emotional in
character. We talk limits but we avoid action.
So how
did we get into this in the first place?
|
|
|
PAST & PRESENT
Conquest
|
|
In 1908,
Henry Ford introduced the Model T. His genius was evident, not
only in the development of the assembly line, but also in the
creation of the mass market. By paying his workers $5 a day,
they could afford the $850 car. Personal, affordable transportation
for the average man (and freedom from the transportation monopolies)
became a reality.
"I
will build a motor car for the great multitude," said Ford,
"so low in price that no man making a good salary will be
unable to own one and enjoy with his family the blessings of
hours of pleasure in God's great open spaces."
Of course,
never again would the spaces be quite so open. The building of
roads and the conquest of a continent were synonymous. In 1919,
an army convoy struggled to cross America. Among the officers
was a young lieutenant named Dwight D. Eisenhower. The army discovered,
not surprisingly, that the trip was almost impossible.
|
The Great Compact
|
|
When asked
about the lack of good roads, Henry Ford was said to have replied:
If we build the cars, they'll build the roads.
Road-building
soon became the greatest public-private partnership in history.
For most of this century, our auto-based transportation system
has been built on this understanding: the Private Sector will
produce the vehicles and the Public Sector will build the pathways.
There is
no real constraint on the number of vehicles the private sector
can produce. Government, however, undertakes to build the roads
and bridges necessary. For most of the 20th century, government
has devoted huge resources to constructing road capacity, to
the point where people believe it is an entitlement.
Consider
the irony: at the turn of the century, good roads were first
promoted by cyclists. In the US, roads were frequently built
to give vehicles access to the first national parks (Yellowstone,
Yosemite and Rainier) and to scenic wilderness (the Columbia
Gorge Highway). Consider the image: roads were wide open highways
to wide open spaces.
The first
problems were elsewhere.
|
Congestion in the city functional
|
|
Rather
quickly, it became apparent that there wasn't enough space for
everyone downtown. The streetcar and the motor-vehicle just couldn't
get along. The streetcar lost. Throughout the interwar period,
transit systems lost revenues, capital and the political support
needed to grow. "Strangulation" was the word used to
describe traffic conditions in the city.
Consequently,
cities were redesigned to serve the automobile. In Los Angeles,
for instance, the Major Traffic Street Plan of 1924 led to the
widening of arterial roads in a crosstown grid. Little attention
or money was paid to the transit system. Vancouver in 1928 undertook
a similar treatment -- another "City Functional" plan
authored by Harland Bartholomew (who helped author the 1924 L.A.
plan) that became the basis for street improvements through to
the 1980s.
The success
achieved by the expenditure of many millions on public works
was short-lived: increasing the traffic capacity of major roads
eventually made the existing problem worse. Wider streets eased
congestion and encouraged more residents to leave public transportation
for their automobiles, leading to more congestion. By 1930, the
Traffic Commission of Los Angeles once again despaired that "traffic
conditions ... are becoming chaotic."
|
Romance of the open road
|
|
The congestion
in the city made the desire to escape all the stronger. Among
the first major urban roads in North American cities were parkways.
Frederick Law Olmsted designed 1,400-foot-wide swaths of green
through Brooklyn in the early 1860s, modelled after the verdant
avenues of Paris.
In 1936,
Robert Moses's improvements to Riverside Park on the west side
of Manhattan allowed the creation of a curving parkway through
upper Manhattan. The Henry Hudson Parkway needed only to be connected
to the Bronx River Parkway, the first grade-separated road in
America, to provide a useful commuter route out of Manhattan.
The consequences
on land development were initially unforeseen. In the late 1920s,
the parkways connected the city (still served mainly by mass
transit) to lower densities and to the amenities of the countryside
-- at least for the prosperous middle-class. After World War
II, the mass-production of suburban houses pioneered at Levittown
on Long Island and at Lakewood in Los Angeles realized the possibilities
of a new way of life for more and more people -- one increasingly
dependent on the car.
|
Cold-war commitment: the Federal-Aid Highway
Act of 1956
|
|
Automobile
industrialists such as Carl Fisher had been pushing for national
routes like the Packard-sponsored Lincoln Highway since before
World War I. The Bureau of Public Roads under "Chief"
Tom MacDonald assembled the coalition needed to drive a public-roads
agenda. Federal-aid highway acts, beginning as early as 1916,
gave the federal government a role in promoting the creation
of state highway departments and in providing matching funding
for a coordinated system of national roads.
The New
York Regional Plan of 1929 had proposed a comprehensive motorway
system connecting 22 counties across three states. An auto-centric
vision of the future was unveiled in the General Motors pavilion
at the 1939 World's Fair, portraying an urban region of separated
uses with unparalleled mobility, made possible by sweeping, infinite
arterials of freely flowing traffic.
With the
Depression and War, pressure on road space eased even as thousands
of new miles were constructed. In the 1930s, planning was already
underway for freeways, styled after the German autobahn system
and pioneered in California along the Aroyo Seco, connecting
Pasadena and Downtown L.A. But the money needed for such vast
visions was insufficient.
As Allied
military leader in World War II, Dwight Eisenhower had seen the
German autobahn network firsthand (contrasting it, no doubt,
with what he seen on his cross-continent expedition of 1919).
In 1956, as President, he signed the Federal-Aid Highway Act,
unleashing billions of dollars through the Highway Trust Fund
to build the interstate freeway network: the largest public works
project in human history.
The Interstates
are the single biggest engineering projects of any town or city
they go through. They changed the econ-omy and culture of America.
The system -- over 40,000 miles crisscrossing a continent --
was largely built in two decades. Towns and cities hardly knew
what hit them.
Unlike
the German autobahn system, the Interstates go to and through
the centers of urban regions, built to the same standards as
those that pass through open country. This required vast amounts
of land and the expropriation and destruction of any preexisting
urban fabric in the way.
Freeways
were thrust into downtown cores in an attempt to give easy access
to and from the burgeoning suburbs. In the end, those same central
areas were weakened or destroyed by the roads on which the middle-class
fled. Retail services, businesses and jobs withdrew to the new
main streets of suburbia -- the belt freeways.
At the
time, mostly good things seemed to happen. Suburbia was the fulfillment
of an American (and Canadian) Dream built on insured mortgages,
technically magnificent infrastructure for water and roads, cheap
land and even cheaper energy. The lifestyle made possible was
broadly shared, optimistic, ebullient.
And Government
was now ahead of its obligation to build sufficient road capacity
to meet a rapidly expanding need.
|
The free way
|
|
If good
roads were good for business, it seemed reasonable that more
roads would mean more prosperity, thereby justifying a no-charge
philosophy for the pathway. Before the 1950s, bridges and freeways
weren't necessarily free: users paid tolls. But thanks to an
aggressive lobby by truckers and road builders, Government created
a continent-spanning system of highways that would, with the
exception of older roads and bridges in the east, seem to the
casual driver to be unlimited and free.
Just as
in the United States, Canadians also undertook to build massive
new and "free" infrastructure. Indeed, Canada was ahead
of the Americans in authorizing federal funding for the Trans-Canada
Highway in 1949.
Vancouver,
Canada's most modern city, hired consultants direct from Los
Angeles who, like Bartholomew, suggested that Vancouver should
build something rather like the Los Angeles system. What they
proposed for Vancouver would have laid concrete on elevated decks,
in tunnels and trenches over and through much of the lands now
sprouting residential towers.
|
The partnership broken
|
|
In an historic
turning point, Vancouver refused to build any freeways at all.
It was the most important thing that never happened. The City
had broken the agreement: no more roads, no matter how many more
cars.
By the
early 1970s, in almost every major city, citizens and councils
rejected freeways that meant the destruction of the city's fabric.
The lack of sufficient financial resources (and mounting public
protest) effectively ended the freeway era. Instead, vehicle
growth would have to be absorbed on existing streets, the heritage
of the street improvements of the 1920s.
However,
by not building more road space, Government was violating an
essential condition of the partnership. Since car buyers couldn't
individually purchase the space on which to run the cars they
bought, there wouldn't be as much room for each new car on the
road. Driving conditions would noticeably worsen. So too would
the cost of insurance, accidents and the quality of life. The
dream of the car -- flowing freely along beautifully engineered
roads -- ran into the reality of congestion, faster even than
in the 1920s.
As it turned
out, it wouldn't have mattered even if Vancouver had built the
freeways. As people consumed the road space at ever faster rates
(a consequence of an urban form dependent on cars and a distribution
system dependent on trucks), the freeways filled up. Cities with
good rapid-transit systems faced road congestion; cities with
great freeway networks faced congestion; cities with neither
faced congestion.
Congestion,
it turns out, is an inevitable consequence when the private sector
produces an unlimited number of vehicles and expects the public
sector to spend limited resources to build an unlimited amount
of space for them to run on. Alternative transportation options
may help accommodate growth beyond congestion, but they cannot
prevent congestion.
So what,
then, do we do?
|
SOLUTIONS
Don't spend money
|
|
This is
tough to say. But there's little gain in spending money just
to solve congestion problems by building more road space. Going
into debt and raising taxes won't help much in the long run.
Building
more roads has had virtually no impact on the growth of traffic
congestion in major urban areas in the United States in the last
15 years. Data from the Texas Transportation Institute revealed
that urban areas which added more lanes spent roughly $30.8 billion
more than those that didn't. Yet the average of TTI's Roadway
Congestion Index for the two groups is almost identical, at .93
and .92. As the saying goes, widening roads to ease traffic congestion
is like trying to cure obesity by loosening your belt.
For thirty
years now, the City of Vancouver has built little new capacity
for the car.
Yet the
result of limited capacity and expensive parking has been by
general agreement one of the most livable cities on the continent.
This is not a coincidence.
|
Charging for parking
|
|
In the
Central Area of Vancouver, we have traffic-calmed neighbourhoods
and eliminated vast amounts of free parking. (In the West End,
85 percent of street and lane parking is assigned to residents,
for which they pay a yearly fee.) Meter parking runs to 8 pm,
even on Sundays. Parking must be paid for in parks.
Charging
for parking is perhaps the only "TDM" (Transportation
Demand Management) measure that has really worked. One result:
the number of vehicles flowing in and out of the core has leveled
off and is actually beginning to drop, even as the residential
population doubles and tourism significantly increases.
People
have a huge incentive to stay in cars when they get free parking.
But to get the benefit of "free parking" they have
to spend over $7,000 a year on paying for and operating their
vehicles (according to the Canadian Automobile Association).
By getting that parking benefit as cash on their paycheck, they'd
be free to chose other means, potentially saving $7,000 and still
collecting the $150 per month for transportation costs that "free"
parking actually costs.
The challenge
is to market that concept to employers, who need to see the savings
on their bottom line. Since a single space of structured parking
can easily cost $15,000, a reduction in need has enormous impacts
on the cost of building and subsequent lease rates.
However,
unless parking is universally priced, those who offer it for
"free" have a competitive advantage over those who
charge. They also escape, so far, the scrutiny of Revenue Canada.
Though a transit pass provided by an employer is considered a
taxable benefit, free parking is not, so long as it unassigned.
|
Congestion is our friend
|
|
Since congestion
is inevitable, given the current circumstances, we might as well
figure out how it can help us.
If the
car and truck are to move freely on a road system with limited
capacity, somewhere there has to be a constraint on the number
of vehicles that can be accommodated. It makes more sense to
decide where congestion is best located, rather than allowing
unlimited demand to erode the integrity of the entire network.
Example:
Lions Gate Bridge. The bridge reached its design capacity sometime
in the late 1950s, and the cars have been backing up ever since.
This grand-daddy of all choke points in the Lower Mainland is
now a North Shore tradition. (The politeness of the zipper, where
several lanes of cars merge together, is actually a source of
community pride.) [San Diego has a version of the Lions Gate
Bridge: the I-15 bridge over Lake Hodges. This serves as a sieve
to keep traffic from Temecula from completely overwhelming I-15
south of Escondido. It may not be pleasant for drivers going
through the sieve at peak times, but filters have their judicious
uses]
The bridge
and causeway through Stanley Park have provided excellent storage,
allowing vehicles to be filtered onto the downtown peninsula
in manageable quantities by the signal system. Otherwise, cars
would congest where the damage would be maximized - on the complex
grid of downtown streets. The decision to maintain the bridge
to its existing three-lane capacity was a key transportation
decision in the 1990s. In return, the experience for the driver
has been improved with the widening of the lanes.
Some would
give no ground to the car; others would take no ground away.
The challenge is to find a limit on capacity that ultimately
benefits the users of the transportation system and the communities
affected, without gratuitously punishing those who accept the
limits.
|
Maximum desirable capacity
|
|
Once it's
accepted that capacity will be limited, the question immediately
arises: how much is enough? What level of traffic do we want
to achieve?
Engineers
can determine the level of service for any particular road: Level
of service "A," for example, is where the volume of
traffic is so low that the design of the highway actually dictates
the maximum safe speed for the vehicles. Level of service "F"
is capacity failure: a very long parking lot with only occasional
movement. The assumption, of course, is that in an ideal world
the "F"s should be "A"s, even if in reality
things are heading the other way.
It would
be more helpful to know what the "desirable" capacity
should be, given the need for freely moving traffic with the
least negative effects, controlled by "metering" points
that allow the rest of the system to function. Metering is already
used at many freeway on-ramps to prevent saturation of the roadway.
Bridges, likewise, provide points where flows can be regulated.
Traffic should be stopped or slowed at certain places so the
system as a whole can function, with feedback mechanisms that
both explain and reassure the driver that short-term delay will
provide eventual benefit.
Once we
decide what we want and why we want it (which is a political
decision, not a technical one), we can then ask engineers and
planners, in cooperation with the communities affected, to design
a system which has a reasonable chance of providing it. We have
to accept that this a subjective process, art as much as science.
These are issues of quality, not quantity. We may wish, in some
instances, slower moving traffic because it's quieter and safer.
Hence the "desirable" in "maximum desirable capacity"
(MDC).
We also
need to know what the most desirable combination of vehicles
is: how many buses, trucks, cars and bikes generate the best
results, given the stated desires of the community. Those will
vary, of course, and so should the nature of the traffic.
|
Intelligent transportation systems
|
|
Even if
MDC can be agreed on, can it be achieved? Perhaps not -- but
at least we should know when we've passed it. Tomorrow, perhaps,
the goal can be met, given the new tools that technology will
provide us. Intelligent Transportation Systems can be used to
manage the system within the limits we've agreed to, and to provide
better information on the alternatives.
Intelligent
Transportation Systems (ITS) take the latest communications technologies
and apply them to the transportation network (highways, bridges,
transit systems and intermodal points), including the cars, buses,
trucks and trains on them, to achieve better management through
integration and information.
Examples:
traffic-signal synchronization, real-time transit scheduling,
electronic toll collection and fare payment, faster emergency
responses, and extensive traveler information delivery. Freeway
management systems, primarily through ramp metering, have reduced
crashes by a quarter to a half. Electronic fare payment for transit
systems have resulted in increased revenues up to a third. ITS
has huge implications for commercial vehicles, providing opportunities
for electronic clearance at borders and ports, as well as automated
roadside safety inspections.
Too often,
unfortunately, ITS is sold as a way to raise capacities, shoving
more vehicles more efficiently onto the road. It's the same old
illusion.
|
What's Good for Goods Movement
|
|
Truckers
can measure the cost of congestion quite specifically, and they
aggressively lobby for more road space to reduce congestion.
But they don't want to pay directly for the additional benefit.
Historically, they've been the strongest advocates for the free
road. Car drivers have gone along, even though they've disproportionately
paid, because they get the free road too -- leading to the congestion
that frustrates the trucker.
The more
difficult but more effective solution is to charge appropriately
for special-purpose facilities where justified -- say, to port
facilities and inter-modal exchanges. The price of the road space
could (and in fact should) be appropriately included in the cost
of the goods delivered. Since we pay one way or the other, the
fairer way is user pay.
|
Pricing for benefits
|
|
Here's
one recipe: Free up existing space by charging for priority use.
If trucks and car pools are caught in congestion, allocate a
HOT lane -- a High Occupancy Toll lane -- for their use. Then
use the money for alternatives, such as transit. [In San Diego,
on I-15, this has funded well-used commuter bus service.]
Again,
technology will help. Intelligent Transportation Systems provide
us with the opportunity to both increase the utility of the road
and to charge for the value received without having to stop traffic
or impose highly visible and resented tolls.
Environmental
concerns, particularly climate change, will help justify action.
When the majority of greenhouse gases come out of the tailpipe,
and every push of the accelerator may be moving us more quickly
towards the vagaries of climate change and the disruption of
our environment, is not some individual sacrifice worth the price?
And shouldn't
vehicle users be paying directly for the pollution they generate?
Industry does. Why not cars?
Pricing
the road and freeing up existing space for those who really need
the room is a far better way to grow for everyone. It has a better
chance of succeeding than the pretense that we will build our
way out of congestion without having to pay for it, or trying
to apply general-purposes taxes.
But, remember,
public opinion may well be hostile because the price is very
visible and the "commons" is less equitably shared.
There must be a demonstrable benefit for those who are charged,
and it must be visible.
|
Transit
|
|
In order
to avoid the difficult choices, community leaders and politicians
often champion increased public transit. And since such systems
are massively expensive, they are sold with the promise that
they will reduce congestion on the roadways.
Such promises
load transit with unrealistic expectations. There are few cities
in the world with excellent mass transit systems that don't also
have traffic congestion. The presence of the former does not
guarantee the absence of the latter, so long as more vehicles
continue to be sold than for road space available. Transit may
help handle additional growth when road capacity is limited,
but given "free" use of the roadway, drivers won't
likely see any fewer cars in front of them.
Transit
investments are still justified, particularly to handle transportation
demand in a more efficient and environmentally benign way --
but, to repeat, it won't solve the congestion problem if growth
in vehicles saturates the capacity available. Transit is best
at helping to shape the city, directing growth to places that
can be designed to be less car dependent, and to accommodate
growth in transportation demand once congestion has limited the
road space.
Most people,
in truth, have wanted the kind of city best served by car: low-density,
single-family, single-use. Ironically, in order for that city
to function without debilitating congestion, it needs a good
transit system, one appropriately scaled to the kind of city
where the automobile retains a significant role. The car cannot
function efficiently without transportation alternatives, and
transit must be integrated into a transportation system where
the car is still considered essential.
|
User Choices
|
|
The good
news: there is a huge latent supply. There are a lot of unneeded
trips in cars. If we get even some of those trips off the road,
we will have solved a good portion (not all) of the problem --
at a very low price.
People
have considerable discretion -- more than they believe. For people
to give up the occasional car trip and find a substitute can
be surprisingly easy to do when people so desire, and the payoff
is big.
Often the
impediment to using other options is that people no longer are
conversant or comfortable with them. They don't know how to use
a bus -- what it costs, how to transfer, what time to allocate
-- and they are not comfortable with the social implications.
Increasingly, they have never had a "learning" experience.
Instead,
the most significant rite of passage in a young person's life
is the day they get a driver's license. By the time they've reached
16, they should already be familiar and comfortable with a broad
range of transportation choices, so that automobile is not seen
as the only option for every trip. Such programs as "Way
To Go," which encourages children to walk and cycle to school,
are critical to future success.
[The State
of California passed a Safe Routes to Schools Bill last year,
providing funds to help create routes so kids can get back to
walking and biking.]
|
City building
|
|
It has
taken almost a century of building for the car to get us to our
current dilemma. It will take some considerable time to achieve
long-term solutions. Ultimately, they can only be found in the
way we build our cities. We will have to establish virtuous cycles
to offset the vicious ones, where success leads to more success.
Fortunately, we can see places where it's beginning to happen.
Take, for
instance, Vancouver -- or at least its Central Area, where growth
is concentrated. The megaprojects that now dominate the skyline
occupy those lands once slated for freeways. Instead of paying
for the capital costs of a freeway system, on which we would
now be spending millions to maintain, Vancouver is using its
capital dollars to build alternative ways of moving about the
city -- on transit, bike and foot. As these alternatives are
developed, we are noticing a stabilization of vehicles coming
in and out of the core.
In fact,
throughout the City of Van-couver people are creating new mental
maps. The bikeway and greenway system -- our legacy to future
generations -- is a hub-and-spoke system, too, only it gives
people who have only perceived urban space through their windshields,
timed out in kilometers per hour, a whole new experience. As
they navigate the bikeway and greenway system, they learn anew
how their neighborhoods feel and how they in turn connect with
other communities in new and pleasurable ways. And the system
itself is cost-effective, mixed in use, flexible, beautiful and
safe.
Given enough
choice, people adapt and the city reflects the changes. Here's
a small but indicative one. At Sunset Beach at the entrance to
False Creek, parking is no longer free. Since the number of stalls
needed is less, the freed-up space was barricaded off for roller
hockey and blade training. It's a win-win-win: Parks Board gets
revenues, skaters get play space, drivers get sufficient parking.
|
Solutions
|
 |
There is
no single solution. Top-down planning can never be comprehensive
enough or flexible enough. Give people enough transportation
options and they can, by and large, work out their own solutions.
That, in turn, is dependent on the design and integration of
land-use and transportation choices.
Ideally,
people should have at least five choices -- feet, bike, transit,
taxi and vehicle -- and the ability to mix and match them appropriate
to the kind of trip and the circumstances faced. The combinations
and the mix make it all work.
The trip
is only a few blocks? Walking is best. It's raining? Grab a taxi.
The trip is around five kilometers? Cycling may be the faster
alternative. Going to a town centre in the suburbs? Try transit.
Yes, the car is perfectly appropriate for many trips, but not
all. Once the car is used less frequently, needs may be met more
affordably by a car co-op or the occasional rental, with considerable
savings.
Of course,
the provision of alternatives assumes a city designed around
more than the car -- and a citizenry comfortable with the choices.
In the end, the answers are found in the plans we have to implement.
Concentrate growth. Build complete communities. Provide transportation
choices.
But to
do so, we will first have to be aware of the impediments to success,
rooted in the unrealistic beliefs and assumptions we have associated
with the success of the car.
|
Gordon Price is Councillor, City of Vancouver, and Director, TransLink; (604) 873-7243; gordon_price city.vancouver.bc.ca; www.city.vancouver.bc.ca.The
comments in brackets were provided by the San Diego Coalition
for Transportation Choices, www.sdctc.org. |