Sustainable development
|
Wanted and needed a new kind of capitalism.
|
by Peter Montague, reprinted from
Rachel's Environment & Health Weekly
|
|
hen Adam Smith published The Wealth
Of Nations in 1776, the world was essentially empty from a human perspective,
with fewer than one billion human inhabitants.(1) At that time, the planet
had abundant "natural capital" of all kinds for example, highly-concentrated
metallic ores, oceans full of fish, continents covered with trees to absorb
carbon dioxide from the atmosphere, and mysterious substances like petroleum
oozing out of the ground spontaneously. The world of 1776 was short of HUMAN
capital techniques for extracting minerals from the deep earth, ships to
catch fish efficiently, and machines to turn trees into lumber, for example.
Now, says economist Her-man Daly,
the situation is reversed.(2) Increasingly, natural capital is scarce and
human capital is abundant.
|
|
- Today there is no shortage of huge ships to sweep nets
through the oceans to harvest fish but the fish themselves are disappearing.
- Chemical factories are abundant, producing a cornucopia
of useful chlorinated chemicals, but there is a shortage of natural mechanisms
to detoxify and recycle such chemicals. As a result, the entire planet
is experiencing a buildup of chlorinated toxicants and scientists are discovering
new harmful effects in wildlife and humans each year.
- Only recently, scientists concluded that the ecosystem's
capacity to remove carbon dioxide from the atmosphere has been exceeded
because of human activity. As a result, they believe, CO2 is building up
in the air, pushing up the temperature of the planet. We are waiting now
to learn the real consequences, but more droughts, floods, and major storms
must be expected, we are told.
|
|
In sum, natural capital both sources
and sinks are becoming scarce on a global scale for the first time ever.
The Earth is no longer empty. It is full, or nearly so.
Mainstream economists do not worry
about shortages of natural capital because neoclassical economic theory
assumes that human capital can substitute for natural capital. To a certain
limited extent, this is true. When copper becomes too expensive for making
telephone wires, we substitute glass in the form of fiber optic cables (which
we make by manipulating sand with large quantities of energy and accumulated
know-how).
However, Daly argues, traditional
econ-omists have ignored the extent to which the usefulness of human capital
depends upon the availability of natural capital. Daly asks, quite sensibly,
what good is a sawmill without a forest, a fishing boat without fish and
an oil refinery without oil? In truth, says Daly, natural and human capital
complement each other we need them both to sustain our economy and the natural
systems that support us and the other creatures. This may seem obvious to
most people, but to many traditional economists it still seems like heresy.
|
Natural capital
|
|
There are two kinds of natural capital
those that renew themselves (e.g., fish, trees) and those that don't, at
least not on a human time scale (e.g., copper deposits and petroleum).
How do you "improve" natural
capital? Renewable natural capital can be replenished by not using it and
by waiting patiently. Fish stocks will replenish themselves if we refrain
from overfishing. The same is true of forests. In this new economic perspective,
frugality, efficiency, and patience once again become prime virtues. As
Daly says, for ecological economists, laissez faire takes on new, deeper
meaning.
Somewhere in between natural capital
and human capital is "cultivated capital" fish ponds, tree farms,
and herds of cattle, for example. Recent attempts to cultivate natural capital
may provide some limited benefits. Tree plantations provide one of the services
of a real forest trees to cut but they do not replace forest habitat or
biodiversity. Fish farms do produce fish but they also require high-protein
fish food, antibiotics to fend against disease, and some means of handling
concentrated wastes. Clearly, cultivated capital has severe limitations,
and it relies on natural capital for its limited successes.
|
Plumbing our limits
|
|
The ultimate experiment in cultivated
natural capital or ecosystem management, as many modern engineers and scientists
like to call it took place between 1991 and 1993 in the desert 25 miles
north of Tucson, Arizona. Here, a group of scientists built a complex ecosystem
covering 3.15 acres under an airtight glass cover and 8 of them tried to
live in it for two years. The materially-closed system nothing was supposed
to go in or out during the two years was intended to replicate a tiny Earth,
complete with ocean, desert, grasslands, and woodlands. The experiment was
called Biosphere 2 (the Earth is biosphere 1), and it was a stunning failure.
From the beginning the Biospherians encountered "numerous unexpected
problems and surprises."(3)
Fifty tons of oxygen disappeared
mysteriously from the closed system, reducing oxygen levels to those typically
encountered at an altitude of 17,500 feet barely sufficient to maintain
human consciousness. Carbon dioxide skyrocketed to levels that threatened
to poison the humans as well. Levels of nitrous oxide laughing gas rose
high enough to interfere with vitamin B12 synthesis, threatening the humans
with brain damage. Finally, oxygen had to be pumped in from the outside
to keep the Biospherians from suffocating.
Tropical birds disappeared after
the first freeze. A native species of Arizona ant somehow found its way
into the enclosure and soon killed off all other soft-bodied insects. As
the ants proliferated, creatures as large as snakes had to hide from them
or be eaten alive. All seven species of frogs went extinct. All together,
19 of 25 vertebrate species went extinct. Before the two years was up, all
pollinators went extinct, so none of the plants could reproduce themselves.
Despite unlimited energy and technology available from the outside to keep
the system functioning, it was a colossal $200 million failure. The scientists
concluded, "No one yet knows how to engineer systems that provide humans
with the life-supporting services that natural ecosystems produce for free.
Dismembering major biomes [ecosystems] into small pieces, a consequence
of widespread human activities, must be regarded with caution. the initial
work in Biosphere 2 has already provided insights for ecologists and perhaps
an important lesson for humanity."(3)
Thus, we know that cultivated natural
capital has an exceedingly limited capacity to provide the benefits that
nature's own natural capital provides. We would be fools to count on replacing
nature's bounty with something of our own invention. The Earth is our only
home and we must protect it.
|
Preserving capital
|
|
Non-renewable capital cannot be "improved"
it can only be preserved. Thus, to the extent feasible, our economy should
shift over to renewable resources, to be used at a rate set by nature's
rate of renewal. Non-renewable resources should be left alone, or they should
be liquidated thoughtfully to provide future humans with a stream of income.
For example, arguably, dwindling petroleum supplies should be invested in
"solar breeder" facilities factories that make photovoltaic solar
cells. The product of such a factory could be used to power the construction
and operation of more factories to manufacture more photovoltaic cells,
to make more factories to make more photovoltaics, and so on, providing
the next generation with a legacy that allows them to tap into the endless
flow of the sun's energy.
What public policies might help us
make the shift to using renewable resources at sustainable rates?
|
1) Stop counting the consumption of natural capital as income.
|
|
Depletion should never be treated
as income. It would be like burning the furniture to heat the house, congratulating
ourselves on the resulting warmth. It will be short-lived. As preposterous
as it may sound, most nations, including the United States, presently treat
depletion of their natural capital as if it were income, so far as national
accounts are concerned a major accounting error. Depletion is a cost, not
a benefit. (The same is true of pollution in calculating Gross Domestic
Product (GDP) we count pollution, pollution illnesses, and antipollution
expenditures as benefits, not costs. This is clearly wrong and wrongheaded
but the nation's economists still endorse such a system a sad commentary
on the state of economic "science" today.) |
2) Tax labor and income less, and tax throughput more.
|
|
We will always need governments to
- Protect the weak from the strong and tyrannical;
- Provide a safety net for those plagued by bad luck;
- Protect the commons (such as the atmosphere) from thoughtless
or predatory individuals and businesses;
- Level the playing field for individuals and businesses
(making sure, to the extent possible, that people start life with equal
opportunity, and that the competitive environment for businesses is preserved
against monopolies and oligopolies).
The present tax structure encourages
businesses to substitute capital and throughput (energy and materials) for
workers. Throughput depletes resources and creates pollution, so our tax
structure discourages what we want (jobs and income) and encourages what
we don't want (depletion and pollution). This is backwards.
After we shift over to "green
taxes" which encourage jobs and income and discourage depletion and
pollution we will still need an income tax but not primarily to provide
revenue for government. We will need an income tax chiefly to reduce inequalities
in income and wealth because huge inequalities undermine the main goals
of a democracy: equal opportunity, a real voice in the decisions that affect
your life, and a sense of shared ownership (a "stake") in the
community.
|
3) Move away from the ideology of global economic integration by free
trade, free capital mobility, and export-led growth.
|
 |
Instead, move toward a more nationalist
orientation that seeks to develop domestic production for internal markets
as the first option, embracing international trade only in those instances
where it is clearly more efficient.
Herman Daly emphasizes this point
again and again: free trade as conceived by the current generation of political
and economic leaders will be disastrous because it is destroying the power
of national governments to control the destiny of their people. "To
globalize the economy by erasure of national economic boundaries through
free trade, free capital mobility, and free, or at least uncontrolled, migration
is to wound fatally the major unit of community capable of carrying out
any policies for the common good," Daly writes.(4) 
|
Peter Montague (National Writers Union, UAW Local 1981/AFL-CIO). Environmental Research Foundation, P.O. Box 5036, Annapolis, MD 21403. Fax (410) 263-8944. To subscribe, send email to: erf rachel.org. |
References
|
|
- Herman E. Daly, Beyond Growth (Boston: Beacon
Press, 1996). ISBN 0-8070-4708-2.
- Joel E. Cohen, How Many People Can The Earth Support?
(New York: W.W. Norton, 1995), pg. 76. ISBN 0-393-31495-2.
- Joel E. Cohen and David Tilman, "Biosphere 2 and
Biodiversity: The Lessons So Far," Science Vol. 274 (November
15, 1996), pgs. 1150-1151. And see William J. Broad, "Paradise Lost;
Biosphere Retooled as Atmospheric Nightmare," New York Times,
November 19, 1996, pg. C1. See also Peter Warshall, "Lessons >From
Biosphere 2: Ecodesign, Surprises, and the Humility of Gaian Thought,"
Whole Earth Review (Spring 1996), pgs. 22-27.
- Daly, cited above in note 1, pg. 93
|